个人资料
正文

书评 殖民主义做法影响当今的减贫

(2024-04-04 04:55:00) 下一个

书评:殖民主义做法影响当今的减贫

https://www.theafricareport.com/321036/book-review-colonial-practices-affect-poverty-alleviation-today/

作者:大卫·怀特豪斯 2023 年 9 月 8 日

尼克·伯纳德斯 (Nick Bernards) 在他的著作《贫困金融批判史:殖民根源与新自由主义失败》中展示了小额信贷的长期失败。

证明小额信贷对减贫做出任何有意义的贡献的责任完全由其从业者承担。 这是一个很高的障碍:一个实现快速经济增长的国家可能会减少贫困,但事实证明,确定小额信贷的具体贡献(如果有的话)要困难得多。

然而,过度小额信贷债务的负面影响更容易确定,例如在印度安得拉邦,2009 年至 2010 年间,数十名负债累累的农民自杀了。

该书认为,通过在商业基础上向最贫困人口提供金融服务来减轻贫困通常只不过是“政治驱动的幻想”。 甚至没有令人信服的证据表明政策努力导致了更广泛的金融服务获取。 在大多数发展中地区,从正规金融机构借款仍然远远超过从家人、朋友或非正规贷方借款。

阅读更多内容 肯尼亚:“免费资金”揭露了经常不露面的外国援助接受者的面纱
失败的根源在于殖民时代。 20世纪初的殖民地官员认为,缺乏获得负担得起的信贷、储蓄和保险的机会是经济发展的障碍。 然而,在西非,法国西非公司(CFAO)和西非商业银行等商业公司抵制农业金融改革的努力,因为他们知道控制信贷供应就确保了他们的控制权。 超过廉价农作物。

世界银行利用信贷作为减贫工具的现代尝试因对殖民遗产了解不足而受到阻碍

与此同时,在英属肯尼亚,合法的土地所有权和融资渠道在很大程度上仅限于白人定居者,而种族则是南非获得贷款能力的良好预测因素。 伯纳德认为,世界银行现代利用信贷作为减贫工具的尝试因对殖民遗产及其定义信贷市场的方式了解不足而受到阻碍。

阅读更多世界银行、国际货币基金组织……现在迫切需要改革

小额信贷试图“最终摆脱”殖民金融基础设施所施加的限制,但可以预见的是,它并没有取得成功。 市场是一种“默认设置”,只需要避免干扰的想法面临着这样一个现实:后殖民时期的金融部门“不是为了向农民,特别是最贫穷的小农或无地农民提供贷款,也不是为了住房而设计的”。 在非正规住区”。

本地解决方案

伯纳德斯认为,金融科技在很大程度上是鉴于小额信贷失败而实现金融包容性的最新尝试。 例如,他质疑手机数据可以真实反映偿还贷款能力的想法,并认为这是大数据信用评分与实际生产活动之间的危险脱节。

非洲洞察

本书的一个缺陷是缺乏考虑当地解决贫困问题的方法。 金融科技不一定与西方贫困金融政策挂钩。 一个例子是轮换储蓄和信贷协会 (ROSCA),它的历史至少可以追溯到 13 世纪,在贫穷国家以各种当地名称而闻名于世。

储户向集体捐款,然后将总额按随机顺序在成员之间平均分配。 其优势在于提前支付,这可以创造大量的营运资金,而个人储户需要更长的时间才能积累起来。

阅读更多 埃塞俄比亚金融科技 eQub 寻求银行合作伙伴以进行非洲扩张
基本模式可以有无限的变化。 可以通过允许参与者竞标提前支付来引入价格机制,额外的收益用于为后来获得资金的人提供回报。 金融科技可用于使该过程更快、更安全。 消除了持有现金的人潜逃的风险,并且可以更快地找到参与者。 埃塞俄比亚初创公司 eQub 是将基于金融科技的数字 ROSCA 付诸实践的公司之一。

《扶贫金融批判史:殖民根源与新自由主义失败》作者:尼克·伯纳德 (Nick Bernards)(Pluto Press,2022 年)

贫困金融批判史:将新自由主义置于殖民资本主义之中

尼克·伯纳德斯 | 2022 年 8 月 9 日

在这篇简短的博客文章中,我想说明为什么对“贫困金融”的批判性研究对于理解新自由主义及其局限性至关重要。

让我的新书《贫困金融批判史》出版。

“贫困金融”一词是凯瑟琳·兰金提出的。 她用它来指代“向传统上被排除在主流金融体系之外的人们提供金融服务的业务”。 对于兰金来说,“贫困金融”这个通用术语是一种勾勒出全球南北项目之间联系的手段,表明小额信贷和次级抵押贷款市场如何依赖于一种“社会空间修复”。 也就是说,兰金强调贫困融资如何通过重新配置空间关系(如大卫·哈维的“空间修复”)以及通过以顺从的方式配置种族化和性别化边缘人口的生存来为过度积累的资本的重新部署创造新的途径。 达到财务积累。

贫困融资的总体标题——指定旨在将融资扩展到主流金融体系“之外”的人的活动——也是将不同时期的一系列活动组合在一起的有用方法。 从这个意义上讲,贫困融资的历史可以追溯到二十世纪初几十年在殖民背景下进行的一系列极易失败的干预措施。

在我的书中,我追溯了这段历史的一部分,着眼于将殖民干预、结构调整时代、小额信贷的失败以及当前“金融科技”的流行联系起来的线索。 研究贫困金融尤其有价值,因为它有助于我们在殖民资本主义的背景下定位新自由主义项目及其局限性。

市场幻想

对于当代形式的贫困融资(例如金融科技、金融包容性和小额信贷的推广)的批评者来说,将这些干预措施描述为“新自由主义”是很常见的。 他们是对的。 扩大融资“渠道”的努力将贫困视为缺乏资金的问题,可以通过为最贫困人口融入新市场奠定基础来解决这一问题。 从这个意义上说,贫困金融概括了新自由主义对建立新市场或类似市场的手段作为解决各种社会问题的解决方案的依赖。

这些“包容”的故事可以掩盖残酷剥削的现实。 小额信贷以及越来越多的金融科技支持的信贷与许多过度负债危机有关。 也许最突出的事件发生在 2000 年代末的印度安得拉邦,最终导致数十名负债过高的农民自杀,并对该国小额信贷行业进行了重大监管改革。 最近,肯尼亚数字化债务的范围甚至促使世界银行扶贫协商小组昔日的啦啦队呼吁“谨慎行事,应放慢市场速度并更加关注消费者保护”。

然而,这些危机的可怕性质并没有减弱,它们也是异常值。 当我们审视贫困融资的悠久历史时,我们发现金融资本倾向于涌入少数几个地方(如安得拉邦,或者最近的肯尼亚),而跳过南半球的绝大多数人和地方。 这是在世行和各国政府寻求全面促进更广泛的融资“渠道”的推动和推动下发生的。

贫困融资干预的核心存在一个至关重要的悖论。 穷人被认为需要获得融资的原因——即由于他们的收入低且不可预测——也是为什么通过在商业基础上向最贫困者提供金融服务来减轻贫困通常被证明只不过是政治目的的一个关键原因。 驱动幻想。 在大多数情况下,向低收入和不稳定收入的人提供贷款、提供保险或提供其他金融服务是有风险的,而且利润不是特别高。 简而言之,实际积累并不按照新自由主义者希望的方式运作。

因此,贫困融资的历史首先是一部惨败的历史,即使就其本身而言也是如此。 如果贫困金融是新自由主义发展叙事的缩影,那么这些失败就说明了新自由主义本身的局限性。 在这一点上,我们非常清楚,失败本身是新自由主义历史的核心部分,例如杰米·佩克(Jamie Peck)对新自由主义通过一系列分散的政策实验“失败和挣扎”的令人回味的描述。 我的书在许多重要方面与这幅图景相呼应。 但贫困融资的历史也特别揭示了新自由主义发展实践的轨迹在多大程度上是由新自由主义计划与殖民资本主义产生的根深蒂固的不平衡发展历史之间的混乱相遇所塑造的。

在殖民世界开拓市场

至关重要的是,如果我们将新自由主义贫困融资干预措施置于殖民背景中,就会更容易理解它们的失败。 这是 tr

从广泛接受的意义上说,全球贫困模式和不平衡发展的根源是殖民时期的,但也从不太明显的意义上说,殖民地领土上的生产和积累组织对殖民地的发展和具体组织产生了持久的影响。 后殖民金融体系。 殖民地的经济体系各不相同,但它们的总体设计目的是将利润转移回大都市,并将生产活动的成本和风险转移到殖民地领土上的种族化工人阶级(广泛理解)上。

在这种情况下,殖民地银行专门从事利润丰厚、低风险的活动,例如促进殖民地和大都市领土之间的资金转移。 一般来说,他们提供的贷款相对较少,几乎全部提供给殖民政府、大型商业公司以及这些企业所在的外籍种植园、农场或矿山。 银行为促进这些活动而建立的以分行网络为中心的基础设施绝大多数集中在少数几个主要商业中心。

二十世纪上半叶的殖民地官员经常担心这种制度对小农无法获得信贷的后果。 他们担心,获得信贷的机会有限会损害农业生产力,这与当今的辩论并不陌生。 他们还发现了许多与当代普惠金融分析相同的潜在障碍。 例如,1952 年发布的一项针对尼日利亚银行业务的调查指出,“许多非洲人希望运营……平均余额较小、交易数量较高的账户”。 此类账户只有在“资产回报率足够高,足以超过进行许多小额交易的成本的(罕见)情况下”才能盈利。 殖民地为促进更广泛的融资渠道所做的努力通常依赖于建立平行的国家支持的信贷体系,但通常都以失败告终。

许多后殖民政府加大了这些努力,通常成立国有农业发展银行。 从非常重要的意义上说,最近的新自由主义形式的贫困融资源于世界银行和美国国际开发署的失败努力,特别是通过将这些机构转变为更加商业化的基础来扩大这些机构的业务。 国有银行是结

简而言之,贫困金融为新自由主义提供了一个重要的视角,因为在这个领域,市场幻想与(后)殖民世界发展不平衡的现实发生了特别明显的冲突。 当前的金融科技实验应该立足于解决殖民金融基础设施局限性的不成功努力的悠久历史,更广泛地说,应该立足于殖民资本主义继承下来的极其不平衡的发展模式。 《贫困金融批判史》为绘制这一领域的地图做出了贡献。

这套图片是位于尼格的联合非洲公司 (UAC) 中央办公室

作者:尼克·伯纳德斯
尼克·伯纳德 (Nick Bernards) 是华威大学全球可持续发展副教授。 他是《全球不稳定治理:原始积累和不规则工作政治》(2018 年,Routledge)和《贫困金融批判史:殖民根源和新自由主义失败》(2022 年出版,冥王星出版社)的作者。

Book Review: Colonial practices affect poverty alleviation today

https://www.theafricareport.com/321036/book-review-colonial-practices-affect-poverty-alleviation-today/?

By David Whitehouse   September 8, 2023

Farm workers in Cape Town, South Africa, January 24, 2023. REUTERS/Esa Alexander

Farm workers in Cape Town, South Africa, January 24, 2023. REUTERS/Esa Alexander

Nick Bernards shows long-term failures of microfinance in his book ‘A Critical History of Poverty Finance: Colonial Roots and Neoliberal Failures’.

The burden of proof that microfinance makes any meaningful contribution to poverty reduction remains squarely with its practitioners. This is a high hurdle: a country achieving fast economic growth is likely to see poverty reduction, but identifying the specific contribution, if any, of microfinance has proved much harder.

The negative effects of excessive microfinance debt, however, are much easier to establish, as in Andhra Pradesh, India, where dozens of heavily indebted farmers killed themselves between 2009 and 2010.

Alleviating poverty by providing financial services to the poorest on a commercial basis has usually been little more than a ‘politically-driven fantasy’, the book argues. There is not even convincing evidence that policy efforts have even led to wider access to financial services. Borrowing from formal financial institutions remains heavily outweighed by borrowing from family, friends or informal lenders in most developing regions.

The roots of failure lie in the colonial era. Colonial officials in the early 20th century identified the lack of access to affordable credit, savings and insurance as obstacles to economic development. However, in West Africa, merchant firms, such as the Compagnie Française de l’Afrique Occidentale (CFAO) and the Société Commerciale de l’Ouest Africain, resisted efforts to reform agricultural finance as they knew that controlling the supply of credit ensured their control over cheap crops.

Modern attempts by the World Bank to use access to credit as a poverty reduction tool have been hampered by insufficient understanding of colonial legacies

In British Kenya, meanwhile, legal land titles and access to finance were largely restricted to white settlers, while race was a good predictor of ability to get loans in South Africa. Modern attempts by the World Bank to use access to credit as a poverty reduction tool have been hampered by insufficient understanding of colonial legacies and the ways they defined credit markets, Bernards argues.

Microfinance sought to make an ‘end run’ around the limits imposed by the colonial financial infrastructures with a predictable lack of success. The idea that markets were a kind of ‘default setting’, which needed only to be shielded from interference confronted the reality that post-colonial financial sectors were “not designed to lend to farmers, especially the poorest smallholders or landless farmers, or for housing in informal settlements”.

Local solutions

Bernards sees fintech largely as the latest attempt to achieve financial inclusion in the light of microfinance failures. He questions the idea that mobile phone data, for example, can give a real picture of ability to repay loans, and argues that is a dangerous disconnect between big data credit scoring and real productive activity.

Africa Insights

A gap in the book is the lack of consideration given to local methods of trying to tackle poverty. Fintech need not necessarily be tied to Western poverty finance policy. An example is rotating saving and credit associations (ROSCAs), which date back to at least the 13th century and are known globally by a variety of local names in poor countries.

Savers contribute to a collective pot, with the total then being shared out equally between the members in random order. The advantage comes from an early pay-out, which creates an amount of working capital that would have taken the individual saver much longer to accumulate.

The basic pattern is open to endless variations. The price mechanism can be introduced by allowing participants to bid for an early pay out, with the extra proceeds being used to provide a return for those who get their money later. Fintech can be used to make the process faster and secure. The risk that the person holding cash will abscond is eliminated, and participants can be found much more quickly. Ethiopian start-up eQub is among those putting fintech-based digital ROSCAs into action.

A Critical History of Poverty Finance: Colonial Roots and Neoliberal Failures by Nick Bernards (Pluto Press, 2022)

For A Critical History Of Poverty Finance: Placing Neoliberalism In Colonial Capitalism

Nick Bernards | August 9, 2022

In this short blog post, I want to make the case for why a critical study of ‘poverty finance’ is crucial to understanding neoliberalism and its limits, following the publication of my new book A Critical History of Poverty Finance.

The term 'poverty finance' is Katherine Rankin's. She uses it to refer to 'the business of extending financial services to those traditionally excluded from the mainstream financial system'. For Rankin, the general term 'poverty finance' is a means of drawing out the connections between projects in the global north and south—showing how both microcredit and subprime mortgage markets depend on a kind of 'socio-spatial fix'. That is, Rankin emphasises how poverty finance creates new avenues for the redeployment of over-accumulated capital both by reconfiguring spatial relations (as in David Harvey's 'spatial fix') and by configuring the survival of racialised and gendered marginal populations in ways that are amenable to financial accumulation.

The general rubric of poverty finance—designating activities aimed at extending finance to those 'outside' the mainstream financial system—is also a useful way of grouping together a range of activities across time. The history of poverty finance in this sense can be traced back through a cluster of highly failure-prone interventions in colonial contexts dating to the early decades of the twentieth century.

In my book, I trace out some of this history, with an eye on the threads linking colonial interventions, through the era of structural adjustment, the failures of microcredit, and the current vogue for ‘fintech’. Studying poverty finance is especially valuable because it helps us position the neoliberal project and its limits against the backdrop of colonial capitalism.

Market fantasies

It's commonplace for critics of contemporary forms of poverty finance—like the promotion of fintech, financial inclusion, and microcredit—to describe these interventions as ‘neoliberal’. They are right. The push to widen ‘access’ to finance constructs poverty as a problem of lack of finance, to be remedied by laying the groundwork for the incorporation of the poorest into new markets. Poverty finance, in this sense, encapsulates the neoliberal reliance on building new markets or market-like devices as solutions to all manner of social problems.

These stories of ‘inclusion’ can mask a reality of grim exploitation. Microcredit, and increasingly fintech-enabled credit, have been linked to a number of crises of overindebtedness. Maybe the most prominent took place in Andhra Pradesh, India in the late 2000s, culminating in the suicides of dozens of overindebted farmers and a major regulatory overhaul of the country’s microfinance sector. More recently, the scope of digitally-enabled debt in Kenya has prompted even erstwhile cheerleaders at the World Bank’s Consultative Group to Assist the Poor to call for ‘a market slowdown and a greater focus on consumer protection would be prudent’.

Yet, without diminishing the horrific nature of these crises, they are also outliers. When we look at the longer history of poverty finance, we see a tendency for finance capital to pile into a few places (like Andhra Pradesh, or more recently Kenya), while skipping over the vast majority of people and places in the global south. This has taken place in the face of the prompting and prodding of the Bank and national governments seeking to promote wider ‘access’ to finance across the board.

There is a crucial paradox at the core of poverty finance interventions. The reason the poor are seen to need access to finance—namely due to their low and unpredictable incomes—is also a key reason why alleviating poverty by providing financial services to the poorest on a commercial basis has typically proven to be little more than a politically-driven fantasy. It’s risky and not particularly profitable, under most circumstances, to lend money to, insure, or provide other financial services to people with small and irregular incomes. Real accumulation, in short, doesn’t operate in the ways that neoliberals would like.

The history of poverty finance, then, is first and foremost a history of grim failure, even on its own terms. If poverty finance epitomises neoliberal narratives about development, these failures are telling about the limits of neoliberalism itself. We know pretty well at this point that failure, as such, is a core part of the history of neoliberalism, as in, for instance, Jamie Peck’s evocative description of neoliberalism ‘failing and flailing’ forward through a dispersed series of policy experiments. My book chimes with this picture in important ways. But the history of poverty finance is also particularly revealing of just how much the trajectories of neoliberal development practice have been shaped by the messy encounter between the neoliberal project and the deep-rooted histories of uneven development generated by colonial capitalism.

Making markets in a colonial world

Crucially, the failures of neoliberal poverty finance interventions are easier to understand if we place them in their colonial context. This is true in the widely accepted sense that global patterns of poverty and uneven development are colonial in their origins, but also in the maybe less obvious sense in that the organisation of production and accumulation in colonial territories has had enduring effects on the development and specific organisation of postcolonial financial systems. Colonial economic systems varied, but they were broadly designed to transfer profits back to the metropole, and transfer the costs and risks of productive activities onto racialised working classes (broadly understood) in colonised territories.

Colonial banks, in this context, specialised in lucrative, low-risk activities like facilitating funds transfers between colonised and metropolitan territories. They made comparatively few loans in general, almost entirely to colonial governments, large merchant firms, and to expatriate plantations, farms, or mines where these were present. The infrastructures that banks built up to facilitate these activities centered on branch networks overwhelmingly concentrated on a handful of key commercial centres.

Colonial officials in the first half of the twentieth-century were often concerned about the consequences of this system for the inability of the small farmers to access credit. In terms that aren’t alien to present-day debates, they worried that limited access to credit undermined agricultural productivity. They also identified many of the same underlying obstacles as in contemporary analyses of financial inclusion. One survey of Nigerian banking operations published in 1952, for instance, noted that ‘Many Africans wish to operate accounts… on which the average balance is small and the number of transactions high’. Such accounts could only be profitable ‘under (rare) conditions where returns on assets were sufficiently high to outweigh the cost of making many small transactions’. Colonial efforts to promote wider access to finance, which often relied on building parallel state-backed credit systems, generally ended in failure.

Many postcolonial governments ramped up these efforts, often launching state-owned agricultural development banks. In a very important sense, more recent neoliberal forms of poverty finance emerged out of failed efforts at the World Bank and USAID in particular to expand the operations of these institutions by shifting them onto a more commercial footing. State-owned banks were key victims of structural adjustment, and the Bank and others increasingly turned to the promotion of microcredit as a way of working around the limits of commercial financial infrastructures that had often retained their colonial geographies.

In short, poverty finance offers up a vital lens on neoliberalism because it is a site where market fantasies smash up particularly clearly against the realities of uneven development in a (post)colonial world. Present-day experiments with fintech should be positioned in this longer history of unsuccessful efforts to grapple with the limits of colonial financial infrastructures, and more widely with patterns of radically uneven development inherited from colonial capitalism. A Critical History of Poverty Finance makes a contribution towards starting to map this terrain.

The set image is of the United Africa Company (UAC) central offices in Nig

Author: Nick Bernards

Nick Bernards is Associate Professor of Global Sustainable Development at the University of Warwick. He is author of The Global Governance of Precarity: Primitive Accumulation and the Politics of Irregular Work (2018, Routledge) and A Critical History of Poverty Finance: Colonial Roots and Neoliberal Failures (forthcoming 2022, Pluto Press).'

[ 打印 ]
阅读 ()评论 (0)
评论
目前还没有任何评论
登录后才可评论.